Monthly Archives: May 2010

Harvard: Lax Underwriting Standards Did Not Inflate The Housing Bubble

A recent Harvard study concluded, "the boom and bust in housing over the last decade was not primarily caused by low interest rates, reduced downpayment requirements, or laxer underwriting standards"

I cringe with embarrassment for them….

Irvine Home Address … 20 VILLAGER Irvine, CA 92602

Resale Home Price …… $950,000

{book1}

Now I like takin' off

don't like burnin' out

Every time you turn it on

makes me want to shout

We keep getting hotter

movin' way too fast

If we don't slow this fire down

we're not gonna last

Cool the engines

red line's gettin' near

Cool the engines

better take it out of gear

Boston — Cool The Engines

The wisdom of song lyrics eludes everyone in a market rally. Prices can only rise so fast in a stable market. Fundamental constraints can be ignored for a time, but wicked bear markets signal their return when the collective insanity that grips the market wanes.

Academics study the problem, but so far, progress in the field of economics has been very slow and prone to decades long wastes of time on theories like Efficient Markets. Greed and fear are the features that move market prices. What we really need is to learn how to cool the engines; instead, we strive to go faster and we blow the engine apart.

New Harvard Kennedy School Study Questions Direct Link between Lower Interest Rates and Higher Housing Prices

Contact: Doug Gavel

Phone: (617) 495-1115

Date: May 05, 2010

Cambridge MA. — Contrary to the assertions of many economists and others, the boom and bust in housing over the last decade was not primarily caused by low interest rates, reduced downpayment requirements, or laxer underwriting standards, conclude Edward Glaeser, Joshua Gottlieb, and Joseph Gyourko in “Did Credit Market Policies Cause the Housing Bubble?” a new Policy Brief published by the Rappaport Institute for Greater Boston and the Taubman Center for State and Local Government at the John F. Kennedy School of Government at Harvard University.

… “It isn’t that higher mortgage approval rates aren’t associated with rising home values. They are,” they add. “But the impact of these variables, as predicted by economic theory and as estimated empirically over many years, is too small to explain much of the housing market event that we have just experienced.” Specifically, the authors found that the 1.3 percentage point drop in real interest rates between 2000 and 2006 was responsible for only a 10 percent rise in prices, about a third of the average price increases nationally during that time and even a smaller share of the increase in many metropolitan areas, including greater Boston, where prices rose by 54 percent between 2000 and 2006.

I reached the same conclusion when researching the Great Housing Bubble. With a spreadsheet, anyone can input the income data, apply the appropriate debt-to-income ratio and calculate what a proper loan would have been. Add an appropriate 20% down payment, and you arrive at what houses should sell for. This simple math predicts housing prices in less volatile markets. Prices deviate from expectations when irrational exuberance takes over.

If banks didn't allow DTIs above 25%-32%, we would not inflate housing bubbles. In the late 1970s, lenders allowed DTIs to go well over this safe range because both the lenders and the borrowers anticipated more wage inflation. A borrower can take on a 60% DTI if they believe they will be making 10% more in salary each and every year. In a few years, the DTI would be under 30% and falling quickly. In the face of rising wage inflation, taking on debt at fixed interest is very attractive. This is the trap of inflation expectation the Federal Reserve had to bring under control under Paul Volcker.

Irvine debt-to-income ratios 1975-2009

Our latest housing bubble was built on a different mechanism: the toxic loan. DTIs were again allowed to rise above the stable range because the terms of repayment provided borrowers with a manageable DTI on a temporary basis. First it was the interest-only loan, then it was the Option ARM. Once lenders started making loans based on the temporary affordability these loans provided, they inflated a massive housing bubble sure to deflate once the unstable loan terms blew up. The terms of the toxic loans were the direct cause of the housing bubble. The reduced underwriting standards merely allowed lenders to give toxic loans to more people and make the bubble go on a little longer.

Glaeser, Gottlieb and Gyourko did find that the price effect of interest rates was greatest in metropolitan areas such as Boston, San Francisco, New York, and Seattle that have less land, more regulation and/or topography that is not conducive to new buildings. However, that impact was not enough to explain the full magnitude of the housing bubble in those places. They estimate, for example, that reduced interest rates should have caused prices in greater Boston to rise by about 14 percent between 2000 and 2006, significantly less than the actual increase of 54 percent.

The authors also found that contrary to the assertions of many analysts, including Benjamin Bernanke, chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, reduced downpayment requirements did not greatly contribute to the housing bubble. Rather, they found that on average the share of the purchase price covered by a mortgage was basically unchanged over the course of the boom, rising from about 84 percent in 1998 (before the boom began) to 88 percent at the peak of the bubble in 2006 and then dropping to about 80 percent by 2008 after the bubble had burst. Moreover, the changes were even smaller among the share of people who borrowed as much as possible. Nationally, in 1998 one-quarter of home purchasers put down only about 96 percent of the total purchase price; by 2006 this figure had risen to 99 percent.

While the data do not explain the housing bubble, the authors do contend that the “the relatively modest link between interest rates and housing prices makes us more confident about rethinking [other] Federal housing policies,” most notably the ability to deduct mortgage interest from federal income taxes, a politically popular policy that many analysts believe is inefficient, unfair, and environmentally unsound. They also suggest that states such as Massachusetts that have restrictive local land use laws could reduce the extremity of its housing price cycles via policies that supersede local zoning or reward communities that allow for more housing.

I like their two policy recommendations, but neither one has any chance of passage.

Diana Olick didn't see the wisdom in this study either, and I will let her have the first shot.

Loose Lending Didn't Create the Housing Bubble

"Contrary to the assertions of many economists and others, the boom and bust in housing over the last decade was not primarily caused by low interest rates, reduced down payment requirements, or laxer underwriting standards."

My sixth grade English teacher always told me never to start with a quote, but in this case, how could I not?

Read it again, if you will; I read it three times just to make sure.

Yes, after years of bashing the mortgage industry for lax underwriting, bashing the Federal Government for negligently low interest rates and blaming investors for vacuuming up homes with no-money-down loans, three guys from Harvard say they're all off the hook.

Thank you, Diana. I am not the only one dumfounded at the ignorance of their assertions.

…I found a lot of this quite hard to digest, given the debate I've been covering for the last four years, from peak to trough to recovery. So I called Prof. Glaeser, who very affably took my questions.

Diana: If loose lending and over-borrowing didn't cause the housing bubble, what did?

Prof. Glaeser: The historical relationship between these variables and the housing market is just to small to explain this. In terms of understanding it, we believe that neither we nor anyone else understands this. The mechanics of bubbles, they certainly are associated with all sorts of irrational exuberant beliefs of future price changes. That's' always been true of housing. What specifically caused this thing? A strange cocktail that brought together things that created the bubble.

It is clear that Professor Glaeser does not understand what happened, but there are many people who do understand it. I explained it clearly above, and I will expand more now.

There is a mechanism by which prices are inflated. Prices do not increase by magic. A borrower is given a loan by a lender to buy real estate. The standards the lender applies and the terms of the loan determine who gets the loan and how big it is. It isn't mysterious; It is how our housing market works. All causes of the housing bubble must be explained by their impact on loan terms and standards. In fact, the failure to make this link is the weakness of all housing market analysis based on macroeconomic conditions.

There is a basic connection between what individuals do and the results of the collective actions of individuals. Individual borrowers taking out very large loans from stupid lenders bid up the prices on houses. The collective action of all these individuals is rising market prices and a bubble. I hope everyone who reads this is capable of explaining it to the Harvard professor. All of you now know more than he does.

Diana: But didn't subprime lending drive prices higher by bringing certain fiscally ineligible buyers into the market?

Prof Glaeser: The subprime mortgage market is different than the housing price boom. We think that it did drive prices higher. But even the historical relationship of LTV is a very small fact relative to the boom that occurred.

I pushed the professor on the loose lending some more, and he agreed that it was certainly an ingredient in the cocktail, but not the sole driver of the housing bubble.

One thing I do find interesting about this study is the conclusions they draw from their work.

So what are these researchers are trying to prove? Well that comes at the end of the press release:

While the data do not explain the housing bubble, the authors do contend that "the relatively modest link between interest rates and housing prices makes us more confident about rethinking [other] Federal housing policies," most notably the ability to deduct mortgage interest from federal income taxes, a politically popular policy that many analysts believe is inefficient, unfair, and environmentally unsound .

Prof. Glaeser argues that the mortgage interest deduction is not healthy for the housing market, and, while he didn't say as much, perhaps more dangerous than low, low mortgage interest rates or no-money-down loans. Why? Because it gives borrowers a continuing, long term incentive to borrow more than they should.

How did the home mortgage interest deduction get dragged into this? The professor is correct in his observations, but there is no linkage to his study. If the HMID somehow inflated the bubble, the argument would have greater strength, but since it didn't, the professor's argument looks like a pet idea he included because he couldn't figure out what really caused the bubble and what anyone could do about it.

The truth is lenders giving out Option ARMs and other toxic loans enabled borrowers to inflate prices, and the Desire for Mortgage Equity Withdrawal Inflated the Housing Bubble. The evidence is clear. And the government's response to the problem with HAMP is simply bringing back the Option ARM. Temporary interest rate reductions and principal deferment are the two characteristics of Options ARMs that made them unstable, yet that is the cornerstone of the government's loan modification program.

If the professor wanted to analyze the problem and suggest a change in government policy, he should go after the ridiculous bailouts and loan modification programs rather than proposing a battle against the politically impossible to repeal HMID.

Problem solving begins with a clear grasp of the problem. If the problem is not defined correctly, all solutions that follow are likely to fail. So far, we have defined the problem as foreclosure, so all our solutions are designed to delay or prevent foreclosure, and they have all failed. In reality, our problem is too much debt, and foreclosure is the solution. When policy makers finally realize this, perhaps they will get out of the way and allow the cleansing foreclosures to go forward. We can only wait and hope.

Irvine Home Address … 20 VILLAGER Irvine, CA 92602

Resale Home Price … $950,000

Home Purchase Price … $1,148,000

Home Purchase Date …. 5/28/2005

Net Gain (Loss) ………. $(255,000)

Percent Change ………. -17.2%

Annual Appreciation … -3.8%

Cost of Ownership

————————————————-

$950,000 ………. Asking Price

$190,000 ………. 20% Down Conventional

5.24% …………… Mortgage Interest Rate

$760,000 ………. 30-Year Mortgage

$202,116 ………. Income Requirement

$4,192 ………. Monthly Mortgage Payment

$823 ………. Property Tax

$300 ………. Special Taxes and Levies (Mello Roos)

$79 ………. Homeowners Insurance

$82 ………. Homeowners Association Fees

============================================

$5,477 ………. Monthly Cash Outlays

-$1036 ………. Tax Savings (% of Interest and Property Tax)

-$873 ………. Equity Hidden in Payment

$395 ………. Lost Income to Down Payment (net of taxes)

$119 ………. Maintenance and Replacement Reserves

============================================

$4,081 ………. Monthly Cost of Ownership

Cash Acquisition Demands

——————————————————————————

$9,500 ………. Furnishing and Move In @1%

$9,500 ………. Closing Costs @1%

$7,600 ………… Interest Points @1% of Loan

$190,000 ………. Down Payment

============================================

$216,600 ………. Total Cash Costs

$62,500 ………… Emergency Cash Reserves

============================================

$279,100 ………. Total Savings Needed

Property Details for 20 VILLAGER Irvine, CA 92602

——————————————————————————

Beds: 5

Baths: 4 baths

Home size: 3,537 sq ft

($269 / sq ft)

Lot Size: 4,057 sq ft

Year Built: 2002

Days on Market: 104

MLS Number: P716076

Property Type: Single Family, Residential

Community: Northpark

Tract: Bela

——————————————————————————

According to the listing agent, this listing may be a pre-foreclosure or short sale.

This property is in backup or contingent offer status.

Attention Investors!!! Attention Buyers!!! Looking to Start 2010 with a Bang? Want the Deal of the Year? Nestled in Irvine s Prestigious Northpark Square & Priced to Steal, this HANDSOME Residence boasts STUNNING CURB APPEAL & LUXURIOUS Comforts that Surpass Every Home in this Price Range! Spacious Open floor plan offers 5 Bedrooms & 4 Baths w/2-Car Garage in approx. 3,537 sq.ft. Inviting Living Room & Elegant Dining Room is perfect for Entertaining. Gourmet Kitchen w/Granite Counters & Chef s Island opens to generous Family Room & Breakfast Nook. Spacious Master Suite w/Huge Walk-in Closet plus Large Secondary Bedrooms offers Abundant Closet Space! Wait till you see the HUGE Bonus Room. Near Shopping, Dining, Entertainment & Schools including community Pool, Spa, BBQ s, Sports Courts, Outdoor Amphitheater, Parks, Walking Trails, Bike Trails, Tot Lots & More! Make No Mistake This Home Will Not Last, So ACT FAST! Only ONE like this!!!

That is one of the worst descriptions I have read in quite a while. I ran out of room for graphics. it has almost every convention of bad realtor writing in one paragraph. Stunning!

Defaulting owner

This property may be facing foreclosure due to unemployment. The owner paid way too much back in 2005, but he put $229,600 down. He refinanced and pulled out a little, but he still stands to lose $200,000 when this property sells. He is trying to short sell, and squatting until it happens:

Foreclosure Record

Recording Date: 09/03/2009

Document Type: Notice of Sale

Foreclosure Record

Recording Date: 05/29/2009

Document Type: Notice of Default

Flipping Trustee Sale Houses on Speculation

At times like these when the opportunities to flip properties at trustee sale are available, it is a great way to make superior returns with limited risk. Today we will take a careful look at how it is accomplished.

Irvine Home Address … 2 Elderglen 60, Irvine, CA 92604

T-sale Home Price …… $387,294

{book1}

Millionaire! Billionaire! Trillionaire!

Hardly surprising, you might consider

Loyalties go to the highest of bidders

What's my opinion? I'd give you ten to one

Give me a million, a franchise on fun

But there are millions who often get nowhere

And there's just one secret I think you should share

Tell me! tell me! How to be a millionaire

Tell me! tell me! How to be a millionaire!

Millionaire! Billionaire! Zillionaire!

ABC — How to Be a Millionaire

Trustee Sales

Back in January, I went through the basics of Trustee Sales:

Foreclosure 101: Vesting Title

Foreclosure 101: Non-Judicial Foreclosure

Foreclosure 101: Mechanics of a Trustee Sale

Next we are going to explore the various ways you can participate in the clean up from the Great Housing Bubble:

Foreclosure 201: Buying a Trustee Sale Property as a Primary Residence

Foreclosure 201: Buying a Rental at Trustee Sale

Foreclosure 201: Flipping Trustee Sale Houses on Speculation

Foreclosure 201: Flipping Trustee Sale Houses to a Buyer in Escrow

Foreclosure 201: Buying Trustee Sale Properties Using Conventional Financing

Rental Returns

As I discussed in Buying a Rental at Trustee Sale, capitalization rates of 5% to 6% are common today, particularly in Riverside County or other areas were the bubble has deflated. The real benefit of cashflow investing in real estate is that the income stream is perpetual, and it generally increases over time with local wages. However, 5% to 6% a year is small compared to the short-term returns investors can obtain through flipping trustee sale properties.

Current returns favor flipping

So why not flip the property and make more than 5% in 120 days? Why not take that capital and flip in and out of four properties a year and make more than a 20% rate of return? Cashflow properties rarely offer investors rates of return exceeding 20%.

The only reason is lack of opportunity, and for the next three to five years, there will be no shortage of flip opportunities as California turns over a significant percentage of its housing stock. Perhaps after this debacle is truly behind us and we have mopped up the foreclosures, keeping money tied up in long-term hold properties is warranted, but until the foreclosure wave recedes, investors with the cash to play in this market should consider doing so.

Measuring returns from flipping

How great are the returns from trustee sale flipping and how are returns measured? The answer is: It depends. Returns are tremendous for those who have the time to do their own research, go to the auctions, manage renovations, market the property, and perform a host of related tasks. As these tasks are delegated, the various players take a cut and returns decline. If a flipper wants to delegate all tasks to third parties including management of the entire process, about half the profit goes to the management team, depending on the operator and the deals they offer.

Calculating the return on investment for trustee sale flipping involves two simple formulas we explore below:

Trustee Sale Flipping Annual Rate of Return = Individual property Investment Return X Number of Investments per year

For example, if each property flip returns 6%, and if that money can be flipped three times, the annual rate of return is about 18%. Both the individual property investment return and the number of investments per year can be managed to optimize the annual rate of return. The remainder of this post explores how this is accomplished.

Number of investments per year

Calculating the number of investments per year is as follows:

Days Invested + Days Idle

Days in the Year

The goal of investment management with trustee sale flips is to minimize both Days Invested and Days Idle.

Days invested

There are three main tasks that must be accomplished between the date of acquisition and the date of disposition:

30 — Prepare for sale

30 — Offer for sale and negotiate

45 — Escrow process and closing

105 — Total days invested

Preparing the property for sale involves renovation and clean up. Many flippers concentrate on turn-key properties to reduce preparation time to less than one week, but this also raises bids on those properties.

Offering a property for sale and negotiating offers generally cannot overlap with preparations for sale. If the property is a wreck, it will not photograph or show well. If old photos are on the MLS or available from other sources, some marketing can occur, but it is difficult to prepare and market at the same time. A future post on flipping to a buyer in escrow discusses how this step can be removed entirely.

The opening of escrow to a closing and obtaining the cash from closing usually takes around 45 days. Lender processing time is usually the limiting factor, and lenders will not start that process until the property is in escrow.

The amateur identifier: high resale asking prices

High asking prices are a sign of an amateur flipper who has not considered the time value of money. Fools try to hit home runs; pros try to hit many singles. Flippers swinging for the fences invariably spend too much time marketing the property often spending 90 days fantasizing before they lower their price enough to make a sale. Even if the sale nets more money, the opportunity cost of missing another turn negates the gain.

Idle days and the minimum investment return

The most important financial variable under complete control of the investor is the minimum investment return. Most investors react by declaring their desire to make 20%-30% on the transaction because they see the resale discounts at auction. They forget about sales commissions, back taxes, closing costs, carry costs, renovation costs, transfer taxes and other expenses. The actual profit per deal is substantial, but not as substantial as some believe.

For an investor to make a large minimum investment return, the bid must be very low relative to comps. Other investors examining the same opportunity settle for lesser returns, and the result is higher competing bids. The greedy investor rarely succeeds at auction.

Jousting with Windmills

The desire of investors to obtain outsized returns creates activity with no results, and it sends people to auctions with little or no chance of success. Perhaps attending auctions is entertaining for some, but without results little value is garnered.

Idle money

If the required minimum investment return is too high, finding a deal that matches investment parameters becomes increasingly difficult, and such deals may not be present in the market for long periods of time. Each day money sits idle lowers the rate of return. If it takes two or three months to acquire a property, an investor missed a potential flip. In short, it is wiser to target three turns per year at 6% than a single turn at 18% because the home run investment may never materialize.

The desire to maximize profit on each transaction must be tempered by the desire to put money to work and obtain a superior overall return through increased velocity.

How low should you go?

Few investors demand returns that are too low. The return demanded impacts how long money is idle, but it has no influence on how long money is tied up in the various transactions. it is practically impossible to obtain more than five turns in a single year; three is more reasonable. Lowering the required return minimizes idle time, but once idle time is at its practical minimum, continued lowering of the investment threshold simply increases risk and lowers returns.

Minimum returns versus actual returns

So far the focus has been on establishing a threshold for minimum return. This figure is critical because the minimum return in concert with other costs determine the maximum bid price at auction. Bidding at trustee sale is very similar to bidding on Ebay. When you bid on Ebay, you can establish a maximum bid, and the system will automatically outbid competing bidders by a small increment until your maximum bid amount is reached. Trustee sale bidding works the same.

In the real world, properties rarely sell at the maximum bid amount; either the property is bid higher than the maximum, or the property is acquired at a discount, and on occasion, this discount is quite significant. A minimum acceptable return may be 6%, but it is realistic to obtain 10%, 12% even 15% or more net of costs and fees. The possibility of outsized returns on bargain properties is the allure of trustee sale flipping. Also, since any property may become a bargain (it all depends on other bidders), each transaction has random upside potential. The incentive is to be involved in as many transactions as possible and turn money over as quickly as possible.

IHB Trustee Sale Investor Reports

Today's featured property is a trustee sale flip active in the market. It is a great example of the type of opportunity available today.

Prior to the sale, the published opening bid was $505,449. It was dropped just before the sale, and an investor purchased the property for $290,000. If we had been there, we would have pushed this investor up to $300,000 before we would have walked away. It is likely this would have been a successful acquisition.

Our report contains the same basic information as the other reports, but with a flip, the only items of concern to investors is how much they will have to spend and how much they will make.

The capitalization rate is presented for reference, and on this property it is very good by Irvine standards assuming this could be rented for $2,150 per month. That seems reasonable for an updated 3/2. But it really doesn't matter because this will not be held for rental.

Page 2

The second page details the costs. The trustee sale fees are based on the acquisition price plus any current or back taxes owned on the property. This tax number can be quite significant on an abandoned property or one where the owner has squatted for a long time.

The real estate improvements are often quite significant as well. Most often, these properties will be purchased without seeing the conditions inside. It is wise to budget for a complete cosmetic restoration. There is always the risk of more extensive damage due to water leaks, mold, or damage caused by the foreclosed owner.

The back taxes are easily obtained from the OC tax collector's website.

Carry costs are often overlooked by flippers, but the expenses of taxes, insurance and HOA fees are not suspended during the brief period of ownership. The carry costs depend completely on how long the property is owned by the investor. The shorter the holding time the better.

Many properties only require minor clean up or perhaps a cash-for-keys arrangement with an existing tenant.

Based on comparable sales, the IHB projected this property would sell for about $380,000. With our constricted inventory, this investor has managed to find a buyer willing to pay almost $400,000. That would turn a 6% profit into a 12% profit. The flipper must be very happy.

If the IHB had purchased this for a buyer waiting in escrow, we would have sold the property for $372,106. The property would have been sold in 45 days instead of 105, but the profit would have been only 6%. That is the way it works out some time. The buyer would be very happy, and the investor would have the funds back to turn another flip. The assurance of a quick sale for a known price is worth it for the investor. It really is a win-win.

The investor that purchased today's featured property is going to make a very nice return. This is better than average, but not unreasonable or unusual. The main limiting factor today is the lender's willingness to foreclose. The amend-pretend-extend dance is not over, and although more properties are coming to market, most lenders are prefering denial to action. That will change.

Irvine Home Address … 2 Elderglen 60, Irvine, CA 92604

Resale Home Price … $387,294

Home Purchase Price … $300,000

Home Purchase Date …. 3/3/2010

Net Gain (Loss) ………. $64,056

Percent Change ………. 29.1%

Annual Appreciation … 106.6%

Cost of Ownership

————————————————-

$387,294 ………. Asking Price

$13,555 ………. 3.5% Down FHA Financing

5.19% …………… Mortgage Interest Rate

$373,739 ………. 30-Year Mortgage

$81,937 ………. Income Requirement

$2,050 ………. Monthly Mortgage Payment

$336 ………. Property Tax

$8 ………. Special Taxes and Levies (Mello Roos)

$32 ………. Homeowners Insurance

$209 ………. Homeowners Association Fees

=============================================

$2,634 ………. Monthly Cash Outlays

-$342 ………. Tax Savings (% of Interest and Property Tax)

-$434 ………. Equity Hidden in Payment

$28 ………. Lost Income to Down Payment (net of taxes)

$48 ………. Maintenance and Replacement Reserves

=============================================

$1,935 ………. Monthly Cost of Ownership

Cash Acquisition Demands

——————————————————————————–

$3,873 ………. Furnishing and Move In @1%

$3,873 ………. Closing Costs @1%

$3,737 ………… Interest Points

$13,555 ………. Down Payment

=============================================

$25,039 ………. Total Cash Costs

$29,600 ………… Emergency Cash Reserves

=============================================

$54,639 ………. Total Savings Needed

Property Details for 2 Elderglen 60, Irvine, CA 92604

——————————————————————————–

Beds: 3

Baths: 2 baths

Home size: 1,165 sq ft

($343 / sq ft)

Lot Size: n/a

Year Built: 1978

Days on Market: 8

MLS Number: S612589

Property Type: Condominium, Residential

Community: Woodbridge

Tract: Gl

——————————————————————————–

This property is in backup or contingent offer status.

RARE TRUE SINGLE STORY TOWNHOME WITH NO ONE ABOVE OR BELOW; END UNIT; HUGE YARD WITH CONCRETE PATIO AND GRASSY AREA; GREAT OPEN FLOORPLAN: LIVING ROOM WITH FIREPLACE OPEN TO OFFICE WITH DOUBLE DOORS AND TO DINING ROOM; NICE KITCHEN WITH WHITE CABINETS AND GRANITE COUNTERTOPS; LARGE PANTRY, BREAKFAST BAR AND GARDEN WINDOW. NEW PAINT, LAMINATE FLOORING THROUGHOUT, MIRROR CLOSET DOORS IN ALL 3 BEDROOMS. FULL SIZE LAUNDRY CLOSET. 2-CAR CARPORT RIGHT NEXT TO THE UNIT. READY TO MOVE IN.

Former owner

I am surprised by the number of divorcees who spent their houses. Perhaps I shouldn't be. The stereotype of the irresponsible, entitled, spendthrift ex-wife is based on observation (from shows like Real OC Housewives), and the property records provide plenty of anecdotes. It is what it is.

  • On 12/4/2003 it appears the wife bought out the husband by purchasing the property for $380,000. Of course, she used 100% financing with a $304,000 first mortgage and a $76,000 second.
  • On 10/18/2004 she needed some spending money, so she opened a $90,000 HELOC.
  • On 1/31/2006 she refinanced with a $467,455 first mortgage.
  • One 5/12/2006 she obtained a $27,000 HELOC.
  • Total property debt is $494,455.
  • Total mortgage equity withdrawal is $114,455.

The lender didn't waste any time once they decided to foreclose.

Prior Transfer

Recording Date: 03/03/2010 Sales Price: $290,000

Foreclosure Record

Recording Date: 02/02/2010

Document Type: Notice of Sale

Foreclosure Record

Recording Date: 10/29/2009

Document Type: Notice of Default

The All-Cash Problem

The reason more people don't get involved with flipping houses is that it requires so much money. The market is all cash. The number of people with available liquid reserves to participate in this market is small.

Over the last several weeks, we have been contacted by several buyers who would like to purchase high-end properties at auction. They have large down payments and stellar credit, but they don't have enough cash to close the deal. We have also been contacted by many people wanting to invest in this market, but individually, they either don't have enough to participate in more expensive markets like Irvine or they don't want to put all their money in one property bear the property risk alone.

Perhaps it would be beneficial to pool investor funds to spread risk and service the buyers we know want high-end properties and perhaps get involved with flips like today's featured property. We are not soliciting investors for such a venture as that would be against SEC regulations, but I do wonder, do you think a blind-pool investment fund is a good idea?

Ghost Estates: Twenty Percent of Ireland's Houses Are Vacant

America inflated a massive housing bubble, but the Irish managed to build so many excess houses that they could house every Irish citizen and still have many left over.

Irvine Home Address … 26 LEWIS Irvine, CA 92620

Resale Home Price …… $620,000

{book1}

There's a tappin' in the floor

There's a creak behind the door

There's a rocking in the chair

But there's no-one seem there

There's a ghostly smell around

But nobody to be found

And a coffin inlay open

Where a restless soul is spoken

Don't understand it

Don't understand it

Michael Jackson — Ghost

Building houses that remain unoccupied is a terrible waste of societal resources. Houses are expensive. When we put hundreds of thousands of dollars of sticks, bricks, and labor into something of no benefit to anyone we get a temporary economic boost from the construction itself, but when no use if made of the final product, it is all a complete waste. We could have sent a hundred laborers out to dig holes then bury them back up and accomplished the same nothing.

This cycle repeats in California. In the early 90s, we had many excess housing units in fringe markets like we do today. The markets are different as the fringe markets moved eastward, but the effect is the same. There are many empty McMansions in eastern Riverside County, the High Desert and in housing markets all over the country.

For as stupid as we were here in the United States, the Irish make us look prudent and restrained.

Ghost estates testify to Irish boom and bust

By Paul Henley

BBC News, Republic of Ireland

David McWilliams is the man who coined the phrase "ghost estate" when he wrote about the first signs of a disastrous over-build in the Irish Republic back in 2006.

Now, it is a concept the whole country is depressingly familiar with. Most Irish people have one on their doorstep – an ugly reminder, says the economist and broadcaster, of wounded national pride.

"Emotionally, we have all taken a battering," he says. "Like every infectious virus, the housing boom got into our pores. You could feel it.

"You'd go to the pub and people would be talking about what house they'd bought. And now a lot of people, myself included, think 'God, we were conned'."

The Irish have reached a state of capitulation. We haven't. Most people you talk to here in California really believe house prices have bottomed and they they will appreciate back up to the peak in a couple of years. The totality of our failure has not reached the masses. In Ireland it has.

'Emotional thing'

Mr McWilliams paints Irish history as one of "economic failure".

"So to have risen so quickly and seemingly in the right direction and then to have that pulled away from us," he says, "it's more of an emotional thing than a financial thing."

That is the root of much denial in our own market. Failure is difficult to admit. Many people bragged about their financial genius and convinced others to participate in the madness. Now they find themselves hopelessly underwater and unable to admit their error. They cover it with anger and condescension.

There are 621 ghost estates across the Irish Republic now, a legacy of those hopeful years. One in five Irish homes is unoccupied.

If the country immediately used them to house every person on the social housing list, there would still be hundreds of thousands left over.

OMG! Empty out the homeless shelters by putting them into McMansions, and they still couldn't fill their housing stock. Squatting is not a problem there, I guess. Who would know or care?

It is difficult to comprehend that level of overbuilding. I remember living in Texas in the early 90s, and I was astonished at the number of empty office and retail spaces. They built a 20 year supply in a few years. Strip malls and office buildings were everywhere — all of them empty. It must be rather eerie to drive through modern subdivisions of empty houses.

The obvious question of who people imagined would live in all these new-builds makes Irish people wince now.

But hindsight is a wonderful thing. Only a few years ago, developers feeding money into local government coffers were getting free rein to build row upon row of five-bedroom detached houses on the green outskirts of towns nobody had even thought of commuting from before.

'Raised eyebrows'

Banks were throwing money at members of the public who saw these houses either as an escape to a better lifestyle or an investment route to riches.

Builders from eastern Europe were working overtime to create homes, the value of which was sometimes three times what it is now.

Sound familiar, doesn't it. How many people bought second homes for their retirement — houses that were to actually provide for that retirement with the inevitable appreciation? Everyone in California was a speculator, and many (if not most) took out this appreciation and spent it like income.

Instead of eastern Europe, we imported our labor from northern Mexico to build houses worth about a third to a half of what they were a few years ago. The pattern is the same, it is only a matter of degree.

As the slump set in, the immigrant workers went back home, the banks ceased lending on the scale that had fueled the frenzy and the market disappeared.

Property supply had become completely divorced from property demand.

County Leitrim alone would have needed about 590 new houses between 2006 and 2009 to accommodate its population growth. It got 2,945.

That sounds like most of the fringe markets here in the US. There are many small towns about 90 miles out of downtown Phoenix that saw huge numbers of empty homes built. South Florida is a wreck.

[empty neighborhoods in Ireland]

The resulting mess is currently being addressed by a nationwide audit of empty and unfinished housing.

It has raised eyebrows that precise numbers are not already clear, even to the local councils who gave planning permission for the homes in the first place.

'Everyone was buzzing'

Ciaran Cuffe is the Green Party minister of state in charge of the audit.

"It's one heck of a challenge", he says, "because we have the legacy of many years of poor planning, and an economy that was overheated, paid far too much attention to construction and was more interested in the quantity than the quality of homes".

Fortunately, we have stringent building codes here, and most of the bubble era construction is very good; however, we certainly got much more than was required.

He says the state's perceived wealth was part of the problem.

"I think there was a view that demand would continue indefinitely at a time when we had very high levels of immigration.

"People thought the housing was needed not only for the people of Ireland but also for others that had come here, and that this golden goose would continue to lay golden eggs for ever."

No matter how it is cloaked, the illusion of permanent prosperity is associated with every financial bubble. The roaring twenties saw a land boom and bust in Florida — there was only so much buildable land there, so certainly it would rise in price forever. We followed that with a stock market bubble built on the belief in the prowess of American industry. In the stock market bubble of the 90s, people thought tech stocks, semiconductors in particular, would rise forever. We were entering a new era driven by technology, or so we thought.

Nobody expects the majority of the Republic's surplus new housing simply to be ploughed down by the bulldozers now.

But Mr Cuffe admits some of the recent headlines in the Irish press on the subject are not completely wide of the mark.

"I certainly think demolition could be part of the solution in cases where we have housing estates that are unoccupied, that are miles away from where people want to live and that were badly built in the first place."

It is rare that houses are bulldozed, particularly new construction. Perhaps 40 year-old crack houses in Detroit, but new McMansions will be occupied by someone even in remote locations.

And indeed, many of the Irish ghost estates are in the unlikeliest, most isolated places.

It is strange, looking down vast rows of immaculate new-builds, taking in their optimistically-planted front gardens and peering through curtain-less windows into unwanted granite-topped fitted kitchens, to comprehend the fact that they might never be occupied.

Mr McWilliams says the whole of the Irish Republic is having to come to terms with what he compares to a collective addiction.

"Everyone took the property drug at the same time", he says, "everyone was up at the same time, everyone was buzzing.

"Now we are all in the middle of this huge comedown. And people are looking around and saying – 'what happened? Was that us?' And then we look at our bank statements and we realise – 'yes, it was'".

The end of a financial mania has all the symptoms of a severe hangover. Nothing is free in life, and when people act like it is, when they become entitled, life has a way of slapping them in the face.

Look at what the housing bubble has already done to our population. We have created a massive sense of entitlement, and everyone still wants to own a home — not because it is a place to shelter their family, but because they see it as their own personal ATM machine capable of giving them everything their greed desires. Lenders try to take advantage of this foolishness and give people huge mortgages. Those that sign up get to live a life of servitude endlessly feeding the beastly lenders. Those of us who do not want to play the HELOC game have to pay a 30% premium to provide shelter for our families because the ignorant HELOC abusers bid up prices. Great system.

Routine HELOC abuse

I have looked at enough of HELOC abuse properties to become convinced that HELOC abuse was considered a wise financial management tool by a broad cross-section of Irvine home owners. Day after day after day, I profle these. I have to go out of my way to find someone who didn't spend their home.

Hey, sellers, contact me if you didn't abuse your HELOC, and I will profile your property and call attention to your good behavior. A responsible borrower is hard to find.

  • Today's featured property was purchased on 12/22/2004 for $610,000. The owners used a $488,000 first mortgage and a $122,000 second mortgage. There was no down payment.
  • On 2/13/2007 they refinanced with a $588,000 first mortgage and a $73,500 second mortgage.
  • Total property debt is $661,500.
  • Total mortgage equity withdrawal is $51,500.
  • Total squatting is at least 6 months so far.

Foreclosure Record

Recording Date: 02/03/2010

Document Type: Notice of Sale

This isn't a bad case by Irvine standards, but then again, they did buy late into the bubble. While the rest of us were paying for our housing, their house was paying them.

Irvine Home Address … 26 LEWIS Irvine, CA 92620

Resale Home Price … $620,000

Home Purchase Price … $610,000

Home Purchase Date …. 12/22/2004

Net Gain (Loss) ………. $(27,200)

Percent Change ………. 1.6%

Annual Appreciation … 0.3%

Cost of Ownership

————————————————-

$620,000 ………. Asking Price

$124,000 ………. 20% Down Conventional

5.16% …………… Mortgage Interest Rate

$496,000 ………. 30-Year Mortgage

$130,726 ………. Income Requirement

$2,711 ………. Monthly Mortgage Payment

$537 ………. Property Tax

$0 ………. Special Taxes and Levies (Mello Roos)

$52 ………. Homeowners Insurance

$0 ………. Homeowners Association Fees

============================================

$3,300 ………. Monthly Cash Outlays

-$467 ………. Tax Savings (% of Interest and Property Tax)

-$579 ………. Equity Hidden in Payment

$252 ………. Lost Income to Down Payment (net of taxes)

$78 ………. Maintenance and Replacement Reserves

============================================

$2,584 ………. Monthly Cost of Ownership

Cash Acquisition Demands

——————————————————————————

$6,200 ………. Furnishing and Move In @1%

$6,200 ………. Closing Costs @1%

$4,960 ………… Interest Points @1% of Loan

$124,000 ………. Down Payment

============================================

$141,360 ………. Total Cash Costs

$39,600 ………… Emergency Cash Reserves

============================================

$180,960 ………. Total Savings Needed

Property Details for 26 LEWIS Irvine, CA 92620

——————————————————————————

Beds: 3

Baths: 3 baths

Home size: 1,856 sq ft

($334 / sq ft)

Lot Size: 5,642 sq ft

Year Built: 1979

Days on Market: 27

MLS Number: S612183

Property Type: Single Family, Residential

Community: Northwood

Tract: Othr

——————————————————————————

According to the listing agent, this listing may be a pre-foreclosure or short sale.

This property is in backup or contingent offer status.

NO Mello Roos! NO HOA dues! Award winning Northwood schools in Irvine. Walking distance to elementary. This beautifully upgraded home features 3 spacious bedrooms plus an office/den with built ins – could be converted to 4th bedroom, and 3 full bathrooms. Home upgrades throughout, bath surround tiles in showers, tile flooring, newer roof less than one year, spacious backyard, premium corner lot site and quiet neighborhood across to park. Convenient location with easy access to major freeways, employment hubs, shoppings and entertainment.

.

Nine Years to Clear the Inventory from The Great Housing Bubble

The mess from the Great Housing Bubble, millions of foreclosures, will take nine years to sell at its current rate.

Irvine Home Address … 57 NIGHT BLOOM Irvine, CA 92602

Resale Home Price …… $629,000

{book1}

I want a little bit,

I want a piece of it,

I think he's losing it,

I want to watch it come down,

don't like the look of it,

don't like the taste of it,

don't like the smell of it,

I want to watch it come down.

all the pigs are all lined up,

I give you all that you want,

take the skin and peel it back,

now doesn't it make you feel better?

Nine Inch Nails — March of the Pigs

I make no secret of my disdain for the banking interests that have ruined out housing market. They operate as a cartel to withhold inventory and keep prices high. I want to watch it come down.

Number of the Week: 103 Months to Clear Housing Inventory

By Mark Whitehouse

103: The number of months it would take to sell off all the foreclosed homes in banks’ possession, plus all the homes likely to end up there over the next couple years, at the current rate of sales.

How much should we worry about a new leg down in the housing market? If the number of foreclosed homes piling up at banks is any indication, there’s ample reason for concern.

As of March, banks had an inventory of about 1.1 million foreclosed homes, up 20% from a year earlier, according to estimates from LPS Applied Analytics. Another 4.8 million mortgage holders were at least 60 days behind on their payments or in the foreclosure process, meaning their homes were well on their way to the inventory pile. That “shadow inventory” was up 30% from a year earlier.

Inventory of foreclosed homes up 20% and shadow inventory up 30%. Those are not signs of a bottoming in real estate. And look at the size of those numbers — 4.8 million borrowers are not paying their mortgages.

Based on the rate at which banks have been selling those foreclosed homes over the past few months, all that inventory, real and shadow, would take 103 months to unload. That’s nearly nine years. Of course, banks could pick up the pace of sales, but the added supply of distressed homes would weigh heavily on prices — and thus boost their losses.

The amend-pretend-extend dance creates shadow inventory. Lenders think they are buying time, but they can only hold back the floodwaters so long. What are they going to do with nine years of inventory?

Think about what banks are doing. They now control the market like a monopoly. They are withholding product to artificially drive up costs to buyers just like the trusts of the nineteenth century. Instead of acting in the best interest of the populace like Teddy Roosevelt, our leaders are encouraging this anti-competitive behavior.

The government is understandably worried about the situation, and its Home Affordable Modification Program has made an impact by helping people stay in their homes and avoid foreclosure. As people who enter the program catch up on their payments, the number of homeowners 60 or more days delinquent has fallen 9% over the past two months.

Wait a minute… People are not catching up on their payments. They are having their delinquent amounts added on to the mountain of debt that is already too large. The government deferments and temporarily reduced interest rates are nothing more than Option ARMs guaranteed to blow up later.

Now, though, the effect of modifications could be on the wane. According to Goldman Sachs, HAMP started less than 80,000 trial modifications in March, less than half the number in the peak month of October 2009. At the same time, a growing number of modifications are being canceled as borrowers prove unable to pay. By Goldman’s count, about 68,000 were canceled in March.

Let's do a little math: 80,000 started, and 68,000 failed leaving 12,000 net, which will probably fail later. There are 4.8 million in default, and they may have successfully amended 12,000 last month. At that rate, it will take approximately 400 months or 33 years to amend our way out of the problem.

All this means that little can stop banks’ inventory of distressed homes from growing. Too many people owe too much more on their homes than they can afford. For the housing market, that could mean a long-lasting hangover.

They couldn't afford it

No spectacular HELOC abuse today. This couple fit the profile of most buyers in 2005, they couldn't afford the mortgage, and they should never have been extended so much credit.

The property was purchased on 12/5/2005 for $648,000. The owners used a $518,100 first mortgage, a $129,500 second mortgage, and a $400 down payment… I am struck more by the ones with a tiny down payment than with no down payment at all. This couple moved into a $629,000 property with only $400 invested. It was more difficult to get a rental than buy a house in 2005. The credit and income checks were more onerous for a rental than a purchase as well. Funny that landlords were more worried about getting paid than lenders.

These owners gave up trying in late 2008 or early 2009:

Foreclosure Record

Recording Date: 09/03/2009

Document Type: Notice of Sale

Foreclosure Record

Recording Date: 05/13/2009

Document Type: Notice of Default

They did get at least a year of squatting before the bank got around to foreclosing.

Irvine Home Address … 57 NIGHT BLOOM Irvine, CA 92602

Resale Home Price … $629,000

Home Purchase Price … $527,000

Home Purchase Date …. 3/17/2010

Net Gain (Loss) ………. $64,260

Percent Change ………. 19.4%

Annual Appreciation … 111.0%

Cost of Ownership

————————————————-

$629,000 ………. Asking Price

$125,800 ………. 20% Down Conventional

5.16% …………… Mortgage Interest Rate

$503,200 ………. 30-Year Mortgage

$132,623 ………. Income Requirement

$2,751 ………. Monthly Mortgage Payment

$545 ………. Property Tax

$150 ………. Special Taxes and Levies (Mello Roos)

$52 ………. Homeowners Insurance

$154 ………. Homeowners Association Fees

============================================

$3,652 ………. Monthly Cash Outlays

-$474 ………. Tax Savings (% of Interest and Property Tax)

-$587 ………. Equity Hidden in Payment

$256 ………. Lost Income to Down Payment (net of taxes)

$79 ………. Maintenance and Replacement Reserves

============================================

$2,926 ………. Monthly Cost of Ownership

Cash Acquisition Demands

——————————————————————————

$6,290 ………. Furnishing and Move In @1%

$6,290 ………. Closing Costs @1%

$5,032 ………… Interest Points @1% of Loan

$125,800 ………. Down Payment

============================================

$143,412 ………. Total Cash Costs

$44,800 ………… Emergency Cash Reserves

============================================

$188,212 ………. Total Savings Needed

Property Details for 57 NIGHT BLOOM Irvine, CA 92602

——————————————————————————

Beds: 4

Baths: 2 full 1 part baths

Home size: 1,821 sq ft

($343 / sq ft)

Lot Size: n/a

Year Built: 2005

Days on Market: 18

MLS Number: S613191

Property Type: Condominium, Residential

Community: Northwood

Tract: Merc

——————————————————————————

A Charming DETACHED upgraded home in a newer community! Superb location – quiet internal lot. Tastefully upgraded with a functional floorplan. Light and Bright Gourmet Kitchen with an Island and stainless steel appliances. 3 bedrooms upstairs and one office that could be easily converted to a 4th bedroom downstairs. New designers dark laminate on the first floor. New carpet. Freshly painted. Elegant Window covering. Nice side yard. Two car side by side direct access garage. Steps to association pool/spa & community. Close to post office, shopping center & easy access to freeway. Walking distance to Beckman highschool. A truly beautiful home!

Irvine Inventory

The seasonal pattern with inventory is for it to hit a low on January 1 and increase through July or August. For the last few years, this process has been aborted by a combination of underwater borrowers not bothering to list and lenders keeping real estate owned as rentals.

This year, inventory is rising as part of its normal function. The lenders are likely testing the market to determine how much inventory and volume the market will take before prices head south — at least while they have some control of the market.

I think many people assume that lenders put their properties back on the market after a foreclosure. Sometimes they do, but some of that inventory is either sitting empty or being rented.

For instance, 92 Dovetail was purchased at auction in late January. Why isn't it on the market over three months later?

7 Foxchase was purchased last September.

77 Olivehurst was purchased last June. At least it is for sale.

Irvine isn't as bad as many other communities for withheld inventory because our market is stronger, but it still exists here.

Latest default and auction data

According to Foreclosure Radar, there are 371 owners that have received Notices of Default.

There are 474 properties that have been served Notices of Trustee Sale and are awaiting auction.

The combined total is 845 properties. That is more than the total inventory for sale today.

That is the visible inventory. For each property that has received a notice, there are four in shadow inventory based on national averages. We know B of A is ramping up its foreclosure processing, and other lenders are likely doing the same, so the inventory of auction properties and pre-foreclosures should continue to rise all year.

Short sales are not the answer

The HAFA program to streamline the short sale process is not how this problem will get resolved. If it isn't for sale, it will not be sold short. Whenever I look through these properties, only a tiny fraction are for sale. There is not much double counting between what is available on the MLS and what is going through the foreclosure process.

Lenders believe they can hold these properties and perhaps get their money back as prices appreciate. The presence of so much inventory hanging over the market will keep any price appreciation in check. And as the cartel absorbs more and more inventory, the pressure to get rid of it will cause cheating among the cartel participants and force prices lower.

.

Future House Prices – Part 1

Future House Prices

For all our wisdom and collective experience, none of us knows what the markets will do next. Like an ocean current or a raging river, a financial market charts its own course. It is fickle and feckless and flows without regard to our hopes and dreams. The ebbs and flows of financial markets are meaningful to us, but in reality they are just movements in price; nothing more. Price rallies make homeowners blissful and renters bitter, while price declines make homeowners gloomy and renters gleeful. These feelings and emotions are independent of movements in price. The market just moves, that is all it does. It is benign, yet dangerous; it is indifferent, yet demonstrative; the market is a paradox which we must simply accept.

During the rally of the Great Housing Bubble, buyers did not concern themselves with the day they were going to become sellers. Why would they? There was an endless demand for properties, and buyers were paying whatever was asked. If they wanted a price above current market values to pay off a loan, all they had to do was wait. Once the bubble burst and home prices started to decline, the conditions people were accustomed to during the rally dramatically changed. Anyone considering buying a home in the aftermath of a crash should think about the buyer who is going to buy their home from them at some point in the future, and more specifically, what debt-to-income ratio and loan terms this future buyer will utilize. This is important, because the amount of money this take-out buyer will pay for the home is completely dependent upon these variables. At most, a house is only worth what a buyer can pay for it. In a declining market with few qualified buyers, many of those qualified buyers will only make offers if the deal is exceptional or simply wait for further price declines.

In a market environment where prices are detached from fundamental valuations, bubble buyers face a daunting challenge just to break even on their purchase when the time comes to sell it. A future buyer must have favorable borrowing terms allowing for a high degree of leverage or they may not be able to borrow the prodigious sums borrowers during the bubble rally were able to obtain. If a future buyer is not able to borrow as much with their income as bubble buyers, then wages must increase over time to permit future borrowers to borrow the same sum and allow a bubble buyer to avoid a loss. Unfortunately, it will take many years for wages to catch up to bubble prices. Even when this occurs, and a seller can recover their purchase price, inflation will have diminished the value of those dollars. If the prices are adjusted for inflation, many bubble buyers will never see an inflation adjusted breakeven price.

How Far to Fall

This book was written as the market crash was just beginning, and although there was already significant history to discuss, the price levels where the markets ultimately found stability had not yet been reached. The remainder of this chapter is a projection of what should happen if the residential real estate market responds as history would suggest. There will undoubtedly be unexpected twists and turns that impact the various variables influencing housing prices, and changes to these variables will change the timing and the depth of the crash. The projections and discussion which follows is based on first a return to historic norms and finally a look at what could happen if the crashing market causes an “overshoot” of fundamental valuations as often occurs in the collapse of a financial bubble.

All methods of predicting future price action rely on the same basic premise: prices are tethered to some fundamental value, and although prices may deviate from this value for extended periods of time, prices eventually return to fundamental valuations. This premise has been reinforced by market observation; in fact, many estimates of fundamental value are based on market action. Since many market participants believe in buying and selling based on fundamental values, there is also an element of self-fulfilling prophecy contained therein. The efficient markets theory is based on this idea, and although the behavioral finance theory is needed to explain the wide deviations from fundamentals real-world prices exhibit, both theories share the same notion of an underlying fundamental valuation on which prices are ultimately based. The challenge to market prognosticators is to select a fundamental valuation to which prices will return, and then extrapolate a period of time in which the return of prices to fundamental valuation will take place.

There are a number of ways to project how far and how fast prices will fall. One is to look at the price charts themselves and try to project reasonable trend lines to approximate bottoming valuations. This is not an accurate methodology as it is based on the assumption of a repetition of past performance without examining the reasons for this past performance; however, it does serve as a useful rough estimate. A more accurate and detailed method is to examine the variables that determine market pricing and see how changes in these variables impact resale values. This process involves assessing current fundamental values to make a statement as to where prices should be–and would have been if there had not been a residential real estate bubble–then estimating how long it will take for these variables to return to their historic norms. Also, there are a number of exogenous forces that act on market pricing in an indirect manner. These include debt-to-income ratios, availability of credit and changes in loan terms, mortgage interest rates, unemployment rates, foreclosure rates, home ownership rates, possible government intervention in the markets, and other factors. These forces do not directly impact house prices as changes in these variables do not have strong correlation with house prices; however, these variables can and do impact the variables that do correspond with house prices, therefore an evaluation is provided of the role these factors play in market pricing.

The timing of the decline is the most difficult parameter to evaluate and estimate. [1] House prices are notoriously “sticky” during price declines because sellers are loath to sell at a loss. The timing of a decline is impacted both by psychological and technical factors. The motivations of sellers based on their personal circumstances and emotional states will determine if there is a heightened sense of urgency to sell which would push prices down quickly. During the price correction of the coastal bubble of the early 90s, prices declined very slowly as unmotivated sellers held on and waited for prices to come back. The market experienced denial and fear, but there was not a stage of capitulatory selling that drove prices down quickly as is typical in the deflation of a speculative bubble. The primary technical factor impacting the rate of price decline is the presence of foreclosures and real estate owned (REO). REOs are a form of must-sell inventory (as are new homes). If there is more inventory of the must-sell variety than the market can absorb, prices are pushed lower. The more of this must-sell inventory there is on the market, the faster prices decline. If the pattern of the early 90s is repeated, the price decline of the Great Housing Bubble may drag out slowly while fundamentals catch up to market pricing. In fact, this is probably what will occur on the national market unless the foreclosure numbers and resultant REOs overwhelm market buyers. In the extreme bubble markets like Irvine, California, the combination of high foreclosure rates and general market panic will likely push prices lower much more quickly. [ii] Even though the percentage decline in house prices is projected to be double the decline witnessed in the coastal bubble of the early 90s, the duration of the decline may be similar as capitulatory selling pushes prices lower at a faster rate.

Price Action

Most market participants focus on price action. The price-to-price feedback mechanism largely responsible for bubble market behavior gathers its strength from an awareness of market pricing, and the widespread belief that short-term, past price performance is predictive of long-term, future price performance. It is a fallacy that is often reinforced in the short-term as irrational exuberance takes over in a market, but over the long term, short-term price movements rarely correspond to long-term price trends, and when they do, it is only by chance.

Predicting future prices based on price action is based on the premise that long-term price trends are reflective of fundamental valuations because they represent the collective wisdom of the market. As with all methods of predicting pricing, deviations from the long-term fundamental valuation almost always result in a return to this value. The weakness in this theory is in its failure to provide a causal mechanism. To note that prices return to long-term valuations without postulating why prices do this provides no mechanism for estimating when prices will return to fundamental value, and it provides no way to determine if there is a significant change to the market’s valuation to establish whether or not prices will return at all. In short, past price action itself is very limited in its ability to predict future price action. Despite the shortcomings of the methodology, predictions based on past price performance are widely used and often woefully inaccurate.

Figure 36: National Projections from Historic Appreciation Rates, 1984-2012

From 1984 through 1998, national house prices appreciated at a rate of 4.5%. There is a strong correlation between this rate of price increase and observed market prices. There is only one deviation from this rate of appreciation during the period. The effect of the coastal bubble of the late 1980s on national prices creates a small rise from the historic appreciation rate and a sideways drift of prices until values resume their 4.5% annual rise. Since prices consistently match this rate of appreciation, and since prices deviate once from this rate in a prior price bubble and return to it, there is a compelling argument that prices will drop to this level of long-term appreciation and begin rising again. If this proves to be true, national home prices will decline 10% from the peak, bottom in 2009, and return to the peak by 2011. This is the market’s best-case scenario.

Figure 37: Irvine, CA, Projections from Historic Appreciation Rates, 1984-2026

The story for the most inflated markets such as Irvine, California, is much the same as the national forecast. If the 4.4% rate of appreciation seen from 1984-1998 is repeated, then prices will decline 45% from the peak, bottom in 2011 and return to the peak in 2023. Since prices peaked in 2006, this method of price projection shows an 18 year peak-to-peak waiting time: not a comforting forecast for Irvine homeowners.

Figure 38: Growth in Income and House Prices, 1981-2006

The key assumption in this analysis is that market prices will resume the rate of appreciation seen from 1984 to 1998. This rate of house price appreciation is 1.4% above the rate of inflation, 1.2% above the rate of wage growth, and 0.7% above the very long-term rate of house price appreciation. House appreciation cannot exceed wage growth forever: trees cannot grow to the sky. People have to earn money to buy a home (unless of course we become a nation of the landed gentry in which real estate is only transferred through inheritance). Over the last 25 years, house appreciation in Orange County has outpaced wage growth. Wage growth has averaged 3.4% while house price appreciation has averaged 6.9%. The coastal bubble years (1986-1989) where house prices outpaced income growth were followed by bust years (1990-1995) where wage growth made modest recoveries.

House prices outpaced wage growth for two reasons: first, debt-to-income ratios rose as people put higher percentages of their income toward making payments; second, interest rates declined allowing people to finance larger sums with less money. Much of the reason house prices appreciated at a rate in excess of its normal relationship to inflation is due to the gradual decline of interest rates during the period. As interest rates decline, the amount people can borrow increases. If people can borrow more, they can bid prices higher. House prices appreciated at a rate greater than its long-term average due to declining interest rates. If interest rates stop declining (which is likely), or if interest rates begin a cycle of long-term incline, the rate of house price appreciation will be impacted negatively; the drop of prices from the deflating bubble will be deeper, and the date of ultimate price recovery will be much later.

Figure 39: Declining Interest Rates, 1984-2006

The median sales price measures the general price levels at which buyers are active in the market, but it does not reflect the quality of what is purchased and it does not reflect the price changes of individual properties. The S&P/Case-Shiller indices measure price changes in individual properties through its use of repeat sales in calculation of the index. Market participants are primarily concerned with how their property is changing in price rather than some aggregate measure of the market. The S&P/Case-Shiller index is the best market measure for approximating the price change on individual properties.

Figure 40: National Projections based on S&P/Case-Shiller Indices

It is more difficult to use an aggregate appreciation rate on the S&P/Case-Shiller indices because there is no single period where a particular average correlates well with market pricing, plus small changes in the rate of appreciation can make large differences in where the bottom is found. There are two issues to be addressed with any projection of appreciation when there is low correlation to the data: the starting point, and the rate of increase. The S&P/Case-Shiller indices did not start collecting data until 1987, but this date is arbitrary. The most recent market low was in 1984, and by 1987, there was some detachment from fundamental valuations. The point of origin for the projection of appreciation may more appropriately be below the first data point in 1987; however, to simplify the analysis, the 1987 data point was used as the origin. The 3.3% rate used in the projections was the historic rate of wage growth from 1987 to 2006. Since people finance house purchases with payments made from wages, this is a reasonable rate to use. Another method that can be used is to assume the very long-term rate of appreciation of 0.7% over inflation. The question then is what rate of inflation should be used. The average rate of inflation from 1987 to 2007 has been just over 3%, but inflation rates have been much higher and more volatile prior to this time. So an argument can be made that 3.7% is a more appropriate number. If this rate is used with the lower origin point to allow for the small degree of house price inflation already evident in 1987, the two support curves differ slightly, but the difference between the two is not significant to the outcome.

Figure 41: Los Angeles Projections based on S&P/Case-Shiller Indices

Based on projections from S&P/Case-Shiller indices using a 3.3% rate of wage growth as a support level, prices of individual properties will decline 27% from their peak valuations in 2006, finding a bottom in 2011 and reaching the previous peak in 2025. This is arguably the market prediction of most concern to homeowners that purchased during the bubble because it reflects the price change of individual properties like theirs. There is very little comfort in the thought of a 27% decline and a 19 year waiting period until prices regain their previous peak.

The degree of detachment from fundamental valuations in the extreme bubble markets like those in California is truly remarkable, and the decline in house prices will be as unprecedented as the rally that preceded it. Based on projections from S&P/Case-Shiller indices using a 3.3% rate of wage growth as a support level, prices of individual properties will decline 53% from their peak valuations in 2006, finding a bottom in 2011 and reaching the previous peak in 2033. Twenty-Eight years is a long time to wait for peak buyers to get their money back.

Price-to-Rent Ratio

Comparative rent is the primary method of evaluating the fundamental value of any property. The price-to-rent ratio links the cost of ownership with the cost of rental. This link is direct because possession of property can be obtained by either method. The cost of ownership encapsulates all of the financing terms and other variables associated with possession of real estate as does the cost of rental. Price-to-rent ratio fluctuates over time as changes in the cost of ownership and terms of financing makes financing amounts vary and house prices vary as well.

Figure 42: Projected National Price-to-Rent Ratio, 1988-2021

Figure 43: National Projections based on Price-to-Rent Ratio, 1988-2021

One of the major components of any projection using price-to-rent ratios is the projection of future rents. On a national level rents have been rising at a 3.6% rate from 1988 to 2007. [iii] This is 0.6% greater than the rate of inflation and 0.3% greater than the rate of wage growth. In Orange County, California, rents have been rising at the rate of 4.7% from 1983 to 2007. This is 1.7% greater than the rate of inflation and 1.3% greater than the rate of wage growth. Any difference between the rate of rental growth and the rate of wage growth cannot be sustained forever; however, the differential on the national level is small, and it can be attributed to changing customer behavior as people demonstrate an increased willingness to spend more on housing related costs. The rate of rent growth over wage growth in Orange County is a bit more troubling. Orange County is second only to Honolulu, Hawaii as the most expensive place to rent in the United States and the continued growth of rents in excess of wages is not sustainable.

The unprecedented spike in the national price-to-rent ratio is clear evidence of a massive, national real estate bubble. As the ratio demonstrates, there was no increase in rents justifying market pricing. The only other explanation which would deny a market bubble would be a dramatic lowering of ownership costs through other means. Although lower interest rates did lower ownership costs somewhat, the resulting savings due to lower interest rates only explains about one-third to one-half of the increase in prices. The remainder is caused by the use of exotic financing and irrational exuberance. Predictions based on the price-to-rent ratio are arguably the most robust because the ratio has been stable over long periods of time, and for good reason; the comparative cost of ownership to rental is a logical basis for valuation. If house prices return to their historic average of the 1988 to 2004 period of 181, then national prices will fall 27% peak-to-trough, bottom in 2011 and return to the peak in 2020.

Figure 44: Projected Orange County, CA Price-to-Rent Ratio, 1983-2020

The ratio of price-to-rent in Orange County, California, where the city of Irvine is located, has shown more variability than national figures. There was a coastal bubble taking off in the late 80s and collapsing in the early 1990s. The premise of prices reverting to fundamental valuations can be clearly seen in the changes in the price-to-rent ratio in Orange County. In the mid 1980s, the market was bottoming out from the first coastal residential real estate bubble associated with the inflationary times of the late 1970s. From 1983 to 1987, the price-to-rent ratio stabilized between 176 and 185, a range of about 6%. After the coastal bubble, prices stabilized in 1994 to 1996 in a range from 175 to 178. Projections using the price-to-rent ratio assume prices will fall again to the range from 175 to 185 before stabilizing. The reason prices stabilize in this range is because it is here that the cost of ownership approximates the cost of rental, and Rent Savers buy real estate and form a support bottom. If house prices in Orange County return to their historic price-to-rent stability range, prices will fall 22% peak-to-trough, bottom in 2013, and return to the previous peak by 2019; however, if rental increases do not sustain their 4.7% historic rate, the bottom may be somewhat lower, and the return to the previous peak would be delayed.

Figure 45: Orange County Projections based on Price-to-Rent Ratio, 1988-2020


[1] Since real estate is associated with high transaction costs, heterogeneity and illiquidity, there is little opportunity for arbitrage (Black, Fraser, & Hoesli, 2006) (An investor cannot sell a house short.) These factors cause house prices to correct slowly without large numbers of foreclosures.

[ii] Large variations in regional markets suggests the markets will deteriorate at different rates and at different times. (Baker D. , 2002) The extreme bubble markets of the coasts will deteriorate the most, and they may deteriorate the fastest due to the profusion of exotic financing.

[iii] Rental data is from U.S. Department of Labor Bureau of Labor Statistics.